

Discover more from BIG by Matt Stoller
Hi,
Welcome to BIG, a newsletter about the politics of monopoly. If you’d like to sign up, you can do so here. Or just read on…
I was going to write about the big tech investigation in Congress, but today a New York judge, Victor Marrero, approved the merger between Sprint and T-Mobile, and that deserves comment.
But first, some housekeeping, or rather, an exciting announcement. I’m part of a new organization called the American Economic Liberties Project, which David McCabe in the York Times profiled here.
As you know, I spend a lot of time talking about fear in various industries, often fear of retaliation from the powerful. There are a bunch of political advocacy groups that address civil liberties; AELP will focus on re-centering our politics around freedom in the commercial realm. AELP will be run by my colleague, Sarah Miller, who is the focus of the profile.
As FDR put it, “We stand committed to the proposition that freedom is no half-and-half affair. If the average citizen is guaranteed equal opportunity in the polling place, he must have equal opportunity in the marketplace.”
And now…
Jumping the Shark
In season five of the sitcom Happy Days, the writers had the main character Fonzie jump over a shark while on waterskis, coining the term ‘jump the shark’ to denote a moment when something that once made sense becomes stupid, irrelevant, and self-evidently ridiculous. That’s what just happened with libertarian antitrust doctrine. A New York Judge, Victor Marrero allowed Sprint and T-Mobile to merge in an already concentrated telecom industry. His decision is fascinating, mostly because it’s so badly done, and reveals, unwittingly, both the hollowness at the core of modern antitrust doctrine and why we see concentrated power across the American economy.
Just a warning here. I’m not going to do much merger analysis, you’ll just have to trust me that cell phone companies like money. If you don’t buy that underlying assumption, then the rest of this won’t make sense to you.
Why This Merger Is Bad
From an industrial organizational perspective, the problem with the Sprint-T-Mobile merger is obvious. Mobile phone services is a very concentrated industry. It has four main players, and the merger seeks to bring that number down to three. As John Kwoka shows, mergers in concentrated industries tend to raise prices, which is a no-no even under the narrow antitrust standards we have today. T-Mobile is what is called a ‘maverick firm,’ challenging the industry with aggressively low prices. Going from four to three in a concentrated market, when one of the players merging is a maverick, is *exactly* what the laws against illegal monopolization are designed to prohibit. Yet Marrero cleared it.
The main evidence against the merger was that executives were going to raise prices. How do we know? Well the head marketing executive from Sprint texted a colleague not only on how excited he was to raise prices after the merger, but how everyone in the industry would raise prices. As it turns out, corporations don’t like competition. Instead they prefer money. I know, crazy, right?
Regardless of what you think about the industry, let’s look at the underlying logic of the judge. The Clayton Act, which is our main anti-merger law, prohibits mergers that may substantially lessen competition. There are various ways to understand what that means, like market share thresholds, but the gist of the law is that if there’s a reasonable chance a merger will reduce competition, especially in concentrated markets, it shouldn’t be let through. Executives excited to hike prices would seem to be evidence of a good probability it’s a bad merger.
Marrero’s view of how this would work out is different.
In this Court’s view, in the intensely competitive and rapidly changing environment in which complex and dynamic markets operate, the anticompetitive business strategies and market effects Plaintiff States predict are unlikely…
Against a backdrop of T-Mobile’s longstanding business strategy as the self-styled maverick and disruptive Un-carrier, it would be counter-productive, even self-defeating, for New T-Mobile soon after the merger to invest, innovate, and improve network speed, capacity, and quality, or to refrain from offering products incorporating the most advanced technologies, enhanced content, and improved service plans, and ultimately to lower prices, as market dynamism would demand and more reliably predict. By embarking on the polar course Plaintiff States foresee, New T-Mobile would effectively imperil its own future.
Marrero is claiming that US telecom incumbents, who pretty much face less competition that anyone in most of the industrialized world and are routinely cited for consumer protection violations, wouldn’t use anticompetitive tactics. He also just believes T-Mobile’s branding campaign - in which its CEO called the company the Un-carrier and wore magenta t-shirts, and imagines that this is the first merger motivated by altruism.
I’m being flip, but it’s just hard to take this decision seriously. At a certain point, he contrasts the ‘market dynamism’ of cell phones to other products, because telecom is complicated. By contrast, “milk is milk,” he wrote, comparing cell phones to what he imagines is a simpler product and thus a less “dynamic” market. Marrero is fooled in two ways. He falls for the branding that products like cell phones, which are actually forty plus years old, involve technology, and so he’s dealing with mystical wizards not normal businesspeople. He also ignores genuine complexity, infrastructure, and technology in agricultural markets because he doesn’t realize that food isn’t actually grown in supermarkets. He understands milk because it’s, you know, milk, but cell phones are magic.
Believe it or not, none of what I’ve mentioned so far is the most notable part of the opinion. What’s even better is Marrero’s view of experts and the law. Here’s how Marrero frames the various paid experts testifying about the deal and the amount of homework everyone had to do.
The qualifications of litigants’ specialists, impressive by the titles they have held and the tomes of their CVs fill, can be humbling and intimidating… Together, counsel and experts amass documentary and testimonial records for trial that can occupy entire storage rooms to capacity.
He goes on to note how impressive all these wonks are with their mathematical models, complimenting the various economists and technical experts who educated him on telecommunications. And then he throws up his hands and says, well both sides have such experts, so I’m going to not care about any of it. You think I am kidding, but I am not.
“How the future manifests itself and brings to pass what it holds is a multi-faceted phenomenon that is not necessarily guided by theoretical forces or mathematical models,” he writes. “Instead, causal agents that engender knowing and purposeful human behavior, individual and collective, fundamentally shape that narrative.” The net of his argument is that court should turn to their “traditional judicial methods,” which is to say, “they resort to their own tried and tested version of peering into a crystal ball.”
The evidence on telecom consolidation is clear - less competition means higher prices and worse service. But Marrero just shrugs. In point of fact, his decision comes down to his belief that the T-Mobile executives were good guys, or as he puts it, watching “their demeanor” at trial.
The great achievement of antitrust scholar Robert Bork, who structured our current pro-monopoly framework, was to subvert the law through the judiciary. This isn’t obvious, because Bork couched his arguments under the notion of bringing rationality and certainty to antitrust. “I use the word ‘science’ deliberately,” he wrote in one of his endless attacks on judges and prosecutors for trying to restrain monopoly. Bork essentially persuaded policymakers of two things. One, antitrust doctrine should be based on complex pseudo-scientific theories of economists, rather than traditional legal notions of equity and justice, or even basic common sense. It’s a science, and if you don’t know lots of math, butt out. Two, antitrust law should be judge made, especially if a judge wants to go easy on corporate concentration. If judges make law, then more democratic branches of government, like legislatures and regulatory agencies, lose power. Bork’s arguments were as much a theory of constitutional structure as anything else, a way to protect concentrated power from democratic checks.
And it worked. The reason we have concentrated power in our markets today in everything from cheerleading to movie studios is because Bork’s philosophy has been in practice since 1981. Judges have been persuaded by the libertarian notion that mergers are extremely complex scientific endeavors, and to stop a merger means to meddle with nature. Marrero has full-on bought into Bork’s ideas, and revealed how stupid they actually are. Lest you think this is some partisan jab, it’s not - Marrero was appointed by Bill Clinton.
Judges are supposed to execute the will of Congress, and Congress has been clear four times, in 1890, 1913, 1936, and 1950, that the antitrust laws are designed to protect competition, small enterprise, and economic liberty. But here’s Marrero, “Adjudication of antitrust disputes virtually turns the judge into a fortuneteller. Deciding such cases typically calls for a judicial reading of the future.” But antitrust is not about turning Federal judges into central planning agents guessing about future economic outcomes. It should be about clear standards to block illegal mergers rather than judges being impressed with CEOs who wear magenta.
There is an upside, here, even though it’s a horrible decision. A random judge, based on his gut feel about a charismatic CEO, just concentrated a swath of the American economy, which will end up raising prices for consumers and hurt telecom employees, probably within a few years (and starting with people in poverty, since prices to them are less noticeable for elites). But in doing so, Marrero accidentally noted that Bork-style antitrust is basically just a ruse, an annoying multi-million dollar costume party of economic experts dressing up in fancy clothing carrying around big stacks of paper while a judge flips a coin.
In other words, his decision destroys the Bork frame that antitrust law is based on economic evidence. And that’s why we can expect Congress to begin reigning in the judiciary, and putting forward clear bright line rules on mergers. Judges should just not have this power. And I suspect that fairly soon, they won’t.
What I’m Reading
FTC to Examine Past Acquisitions by Large Technology Companies, FTC The Federal Trade Commission is doing a study of Apple, Google, Facebook, Amazon, and Microsoft and their mergers from 2010-2019. This cuts against the Sprint-T-Mobile decision, because it will give us actual empirical evidence on how mergers work in practice.
Boeing Booked No New Jetliner Orders in January, WSJ - Looks like Boeing is feeling strain…
DOJ seeks 71 percent bump from Congress for antitrust, Politico A pro-monopoly Department of Justice Antitrust Division wants more money?
Uber fails to block California gig economy law, FT
Chairman Jerry Nadler of the House Judiciary Committee noted in Brooklyn that the House Antitrust Subcommittee investigation into big tech is serious.

Thanks for reading. And if you liked this essay, you can sign up here for more issues of BIG, a newsletter on how to restore fair commerce, innovation and democracy. If you want to really understand the secret history of monopoly power, read my book, Goliath: The 100-Year War Between Monopoly Power and Democracy.
cheers,
Matt Stoller
The Sprint-T-Mobile Merger: A Jump the Shark Moment for Antitrust?
This is a classic case of technical vs cultural rationality. Experts on both sides of the argument use the same (or similar) data to come to different conclusions, and Judge Marrero sitting in the middle has to use 'cultural rationality' to determine how to decide which expert to believe. That is to say, since he doesn't have the expert-level training required to figure out which expert to believe he needs to use conventional methods such as 'trustworthiness' to ascertain who to rule for/against. Note that if Judge Marrero was himself an expert, we wouldn't need the experts in the first place.
For a more in-depth background, you can find technical & cultural rationality outlined here [1] and here [2].
The solution outlined by Wayne in [2], is to switch the focus from having the experts present the data and their conclusions to citizens (in this case, Judge Marrero), but instead interpret their findings with the goal of educating and informing so that an educated decision can be reached by the citizen (Judge Marrero).
[1] https://www.jstor.org/stable/689375
[2] https://www.researchgate.net/publication/277396318_Science_and_Citizens_Globalization_and_the_Challenge_of_Engagement
Sorry, this is going to be long. I'm catching up, having discovered your blog a couple months ago. Judges creating policy is so fascist. Pricing doctrine for "middle-class luxuries" reflects the loss of control the middle class has suffered re: cost of living. Two personal experiences to back up the idea of a pricing doctrine that reflects a fascist system. I pay $70/month for $35 internet service from Verizon, my only option, in NY state. The breakdown of my bill, depending on the month, will include: tons of taxes at both state and federal levels; an "Undisclosed" fee, usually around $2.50 (!!!); one month, a $7.50 chip-in for, "Federal Subscriber Line Charge...to partially reimburse long distance companies for the cost of routing long distance calls to and from local customers," (!!!), and another month, a different "NY Municipal Construction Surcharge... [to recover] a portion of the expenses Verizon incurs for relocation of its facilities that are in the public rights-of-way to prevent interference with street repairs, public construction projects or other activities required for public health, safety or convenience," at $2.49 (!!!). And for that $35.00 internet, I spent $413.94 in total over the first three months to cover the monthly price, installation and activation fees, and equipment costs. Second, when I got my dog neutered, I discovered, upon closely reviewing my bill, that my vet assumed that I would want drugs it would need in 1 out of 100 cases dispensed beforehand; that I would want to add $50 for a type of thread for stitches that dissolves in three days instead of seven; and something else I'm forgetting. IMO, the most likely explanations for greed reflected in pricing structures on one hand, and the need to up-sell to survive on the other, are that 1- the system governing capital distribution is corrupt, whereby elections, through a whole plethora of levers, are attached to corporate outcomes; and 2- governing bodies made up of elites aren't reading their phone bills closely AND asking themselves what these bills must feel like to average people. Why are elites so selfish? That's another question worth asking, and I think it is something society will have to reckon with sooner or later.